Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model
Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical po...
Ausführliche Beschreibung
Autor*in: |
Eckehard Rosenbaum [verfasserIn] |
---|
Format: |
Artikel |
---|---|
Sprache: |
Englisch |
Erschienen: |
2015 |
---|
Schlagwörter: |
---|
Übergeordnetes Werk: |
Enthalten in: Journal of post-Keynesian economics - Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978, 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 |
---|---|
Übergeordnetes Werk: |
volume:37 ; year:2015 ; number:4 ; pages:623 |
Links: |
---|
Katalog-ID: |
OLC1968006443 |
---|
LEADER | 01000caa a2200265 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
001 | OLC1968006443 | ||
003 | DE-627 | ||
005 | 20230714171835.0 | ||
007 | tu | ||
008 | 160206s2015 xx ||||| 00| ||eng c | ||
028 | 5 | 2 | |a PQ20160617 |
035 | |a (DE-627)OLC1968006443 | ||
035 | |a (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 | ||
035 | |a (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 | ||
035 | |a (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt | ||
040 | |a DE-627 |b ger |c DE-627 |e rakwb | ||
041 | |a eng | ||
082 | 0 | 4 | |a 17 |a 330 |a 380 |a 650 |a 670 |q DNB |
082 | 0 | 4 | |a 300 |q AVZ |
100 | 0 | |a Eckehard Rosenbaum |e verfasserin |4 aut | |
245 | 1 | 0 | |a Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model |
264 | 1 | |c 2015 | |
336 | |a Text |b txt |2 rdacontent | ||
337 | |a ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen |b n |2 rdamedia | ||
338 | |a Band |b nc |2 rdacarrier | ||
520 | |a Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. | ||
650 | 4 | |a Growth rate | |
650 | 4 | |a Growth models | |
650 | 4 | |a Studies | |
650 | 4 | |a Economic growth | |
650 | 4 | |a Recessions | |
650 | 4 | |a Keynesian theory | |
773 | 0 | 8 | |i Enthalten in |t Journal of post-Keynesian economics |d Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978 |g 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 |w (DE-627)130055077 |w (DE-600)436253-6 |w (DE-576)015592626 |x 0160-3477 |7 nnns |
773 | 1 | 8 | |g volume:37 |g year:2015 |g number:4 |g pages:623 |
856 | 4 | 2 | |u http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 |
912 | |a GBV_USEFLAG_A | ||
912 | |a SYSFLAG_A | ||
912 | |a GBV_OLC | ||
912 | |a SSG-OLC-WIW | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_11 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_21 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_26 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_70 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_2020 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4012 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4125 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4317 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4318 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4335 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4700 | ||
951 | |a AR | ||
952 | |d 37 |j 2015 |e 4 |h 623 |
author_variant |
e r er |
---|---|
matchkey_str |
article:01603477:2015----::eorwhnsrcuacagiaotens |
hierarchy_sort_str |
2015 |
publishDate |
2015 |
allfields |
PQ20160617 (DE-627)OLC1968006443 (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ Eckehard Rosenbaum verfasserin aut Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model 2015 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 (DE-627)130055077 (DE-600)436253-6 (DE-576)015592626 0160-3477 nnns volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_11 GBV_ILN_21 GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_2020 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4125 GBV_ILN_4317 GBV_ILN_4318 GBV_ILN_4335 GBV_ILN_4700 AR 37 2015 4 623 |
spelling |
PQ20160617 (DE-627)OLC1968006443 (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ Eckehard Rosenbaum verfasserin aut Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model 2015 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 (DE-627)130055077 (DE-600)436253-6 (DE-576)015592626 0160-3477 nnns volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_11 GBV_ILN_21 GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_2020 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4125 GBV_ILN_4317 GBV_ILN_4318 GBV_ILN_4335 GBV_ILN_4700 AR 37 2015 4 623 |
allfields_unstemmed |
PQ20160617 (DE-627)OLC1968006443 (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ Eckehard Rosenbaum verfasserin aut Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model 2015 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 (DE-627)130055077 (DE-600)436253-6 (DE-576)015592626 0160-3477 nnns volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_11 GBV_ILN_21 GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_2020 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4125 GBV_ILN_4317 GBV_ILN_4318 GBV_ILN_4335 GBV_ILN_4700 AR 37 2015 4 623 |
allfieldsGer |
PQ20160617 (DE-627)OLC1968006443 (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ Eckehard Rosenbaum verfasserin aut Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model 2015 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 (DE-627)130055077 (DE-600)436253-6 (DE-576)015592626 0160-3477 nnns volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_11 GBV_ILN_21 GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_2020 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4125 GBV_ILN_4317 GBV_ILN_4318 GBV_ILN_4335 GBV_ILN_4700 AR 37 2015 4 623 |
allfieldsSound |
PQ20160617 (DE-627)OLC1968006443 (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ Eckehard Rosenbaum verfasserin aut Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model 2015 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 (DE-627)130055077 (DE-600)436253-6 (DE-576)015592626 0160-3477 nnns volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_11 GBV_ILN_21 GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_2020 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4125 GBV_ILN_4317 GBV_ILN_4318 GBV_ILN_4335 GBV_ILN_4700 AR 37 2015 4 623 |
language |
English |
source |
Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 |
sourceStr |
Enthalten in Journal of post-Keynesian economics 37(2015), 4, Seite 623 volume:37 year:2015 number:4 pages:623 |
format_phy_str_mv |
Article |
institution |
findex.gbv.de |
topic_facet |
Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory |
dewey-raw |
17 |
isfreeaccess_bool |
false |
container_title |
Journal of post-Keynesian economics |
authorswithroles_txt_mv |
Eckehard Rosenbaum @@aut@@ |
publishDateDaySort_date |
2015-01-01T00:00:00Z |
hierarchy_top_id |
130055077 |
dewey-sort |
217 |
id |
OLC1968006443 |
language_de |
englisch |
fullrecord |
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim"><record><leader>01000caa a2200265 4500</leader><controlfield tag="001">OLC1968006443</controlfield><controlfield tag="003">DE-627</controlfield><controlfield tag="005">20230714171835.0</controlfield><controlfield tag="007">tu</controlfield><controlfield tag="008">160206s2015 xx ||||| 00| ||eng c</controlfield><datafield tag="028" ind1="5" ind2="2"><subfield code="a">PQ20160617</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-627)OLC1968006443</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="b">ger</subfield><subfield code="c">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="e">rakwb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="041" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">eng</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="082" ind1="0" ind2="4"><subfield code="a">17</subfield><subfield code="a">330</subfield><subfield code="a">380</subfield><subfield code="a">650</subfield><subfield code="a">670</subfield><subfield code="q">DNB</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="082" ind1="0" ind2="4"><subfield code="a">300</subfield><subfield code="q">AVZ</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="100" ind1="0" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Eckehard Rosenbaum</subfield><subfield code="e">verfasserin</subfield><subfield code="4">aut</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0"><subfield code="a">Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="264" ind1=" " ind2="1"><subfield code="c">2015</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="336" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Text</subfield><subfield code="b">txt</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacontent</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="337" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen</subfield><subfield code="b">n</subfield><subfield code="2">rdamedia</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="338" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Band</subfield><subfield code="b">nc</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacarrier</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth.</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Growth rate</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Growth models</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Studies</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economic growth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Recessions</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Keynesian theory</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2="8"><subfield code="i">Enthalten in</subfield><subfield code="t">Journal of post-Keynesian economics</subfield><subfield code="d">Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978</subfield><subfield code="g">37(2015), 4, Seite 623</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-627)130055077</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-600)436253-6</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-576)015592626</subfield><subfield code="x">0160-3477</subfield><subfield code="7">nnns</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="1" ind2="8"><subfield code="g">volume:37</subfield><subfield code="g">year:2015</subfield><subfield code="g">number:4</subfield><subfield code="g">pages:623</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="2"><subfield code="u">http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_USEFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SYSFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_OLC</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SSG-OLC-WIW</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_11</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_21</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_26</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_70</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_2020</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4012</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4125</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4317</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4318</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4335</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4700</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="951" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">AR</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="952" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="d">37</subfield><subfield code="j">2015</subfield><subfield code="e">4</subfield><subfield code="h">623</subfield></datafield></record></collection>
|
author |
Eckehard Rosenbaum |
spellingShingle |
Eckehard Rosenbaum ddc 17 ddc 300 misc Growth rate misc Growth models misc Studies misc Economic growth misc Recessions misc Keynesian theory Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model |
authorStr |
Eckehard Rosenbaum |
ppnlink_with_tag_str_mv |
@@773@@(DE-627)130055077 |
format |
Article |
dewey-ones |
017 - General subject catalogs 330 - Economics 380 - Commerce, communications & transportation 650 - Management & auxiliary services 670 - Manufacturing 300 - Social sciences |
delete_txt_mv |
keep |
author_role |
aut |
collection |
OLC |
remote_str |
false |
illustrated |
Not Illustrated |
issn |
0160-3477 |
topic_title |
17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model Growth rate Growth models Studies Economic growth Recessions Keynesian theory |
topic |
ddc 17 ddc 300 misc Growth rate misc Growth models misc Studies misc Economic growth misc Recessions misc Keynesian theory |
topic_unstemmed |
ddc 17 ddc 300 misc Growth rate misc Growth models misc Studies misc Economic growth misc Recessions misc Keynesian theory |
topic_browse |
ddc 17 ddc 300 misc Growth rate misc Growth models misc Studies misc Economic growth misc Recessions misc Keynesian theory |
format_facet |
Aufsätze Gedruckte Aufsätze |
format_main_str_mv |
Text Zeitschrift/Artikel |
carriertype_str_mv |
nc |
hierarchy_parent_title |
Journal of post-Keynesian economics |
hierarchy_parent_id |
130055077 |
dewey-tens |
010 - Bibliographies 330 - Economics 380 - Commerce, communications & transportation 650 - Management & public relations 670 - Manufacturing 300 - Social sciences, sociology & anthropology |
hierarchy_top_title |
Journal of post-Keynesian economics |
isfreeaccess_txt |
false |
familylinks_str_mv |
(DE-627)130055077 (DE-600)436253-6 (DE-576)015592626 |
title |
Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model |
ctrlnum |
(DE-627)OLC1968006443 (DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443 (PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0 (KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt |
title_full |
Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model |
author_sort |
Eckehard Rosenbaum |
journal |
Journal of post-Keynesian economics |
journalStr |
Journal of post-Keynesian economics |
lang_code |
eng |
isOA_bool |
false |
dewey-hundreds |
000 - Computer science, information & general works 300 - Social sciences 600 - Technology |
recordtype |
marc |
publishDateSort |
2015 |
contenttype_str_mv |
txt |
container_start_page |
623 |
author_browse |
Eckehard Rosenbaum |
container_volume |
37 |
class |
17 330 380 650 670 DNB 300 AVZ |
format_se |
Aufsätze |
author-letter |
Eckehard Rosenbaum |
dewey-full |
17 330 380 650 670 300 |
title_sort |
zero growth and structural change in a post keynesian growth model |
title_auth |
Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model |
abstract |
Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. |
abstractGer |
Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. |
abstract_unstemmed |
Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth. |
collection_details |
GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_11 GBV_ILN_21 GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_2020 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4125 GBV_ILN_4317 GBV_ILN_4318 GBV_ILN_4335 GBV_ILN_4700 |
container_issue |
4 |
title_short |
Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model |
url |
http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527 |
remote_bool |
false |
ppnlink |
130055077 |
mediatype_str_mv |
n |
isOA_txt |
false |
hochschulschrift_bool |
false |
up_date |
2024-07-04T02:24:26.656Z |
_version_ |
1803613494739730432 |
fullrecord_marcxml |
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim"><record><leader>01000caa a2200265 4500</leader><controlfield tag="001">OLC1968006443</controlfield><controlfield tag="003">DE-627</controlfield><controlfield tag="005">20230714171835.0</controlfield><controlfield tag="007">tu</controlfield><controlfield tag="008">160206s2015 xx ||||| 00| ||eng c</controlfield><datafield tag="028" ind1="5" ind2="2"><subfield code="a">PQ20160617</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-627)OLC1968006443</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-599)GBVOLC1968006443</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(PRQ)p1116-2108dcd741cf2a6acccef5bd977897614e07337a0091590fa61d2cb19f5710cc0</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(KEY)0090374420150000037000400623zerogrowthandstructuralchangeinapostkeynesiangrowt</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="b">ger</subfield><subfield code="c">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="e">rakwb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="041" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">eng</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="082" ind1="0" ind2="4"><subfield code="a">17</subfield><subfield code="a">330</subfield><subfield code="a">380</subfield><subfield code="a">650</subfield><subfield code="a">670</subfield><subfield code="q">DNB</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="082" ind1="0" ind2="4"><subfield code="a">300</subfield><subfield code="q">AVZ</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="100" ind1="0" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Eckehard Rosenbaum</subfield><subfield code="e">verfasserin</subfield><subfield code="4">aut</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0"><subfield code="a">Zero growth and structural change in a post Keynesian growth model</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="264" ind1=" " ind2="1"><subfield code="c">2015</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="336" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Text</subfield><subfield code="b">txt</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacontent</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="337" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen</subfield><subfield code="b">n</subfield><subfield code="2">rdamedia</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="338" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Band</subfield><subfield code="b">nc</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacarrier</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Continuous albeit oscillating economic growth has become a hallmark of modern economies. Arguing on the basis of theoretical models, some authors maintain that growth is even a systemic requirement of capitalist economies. Thus the latter remain only stable as long as they grow. From an empirical point of view, phases of negative growth (recessions) often go hand in hand with economically and socially detrimental side effects, which policymakers seek to avoid at virtually all costs. This is why a stagnant or even degrowing economy is also anathema to policymakers and arguably to the public at large. Concomitantly, economic research has focused mainly on the drivers of growth rather than the conditions under which stagnant economies can exist. The present paper seeks to contribute to the analysis of stagnant economies by investigating the interrelationship of zero growth and technological progress in the context of a Kaleckian growth model. The analysis starts by showing that a Kaleckian model allows zero growth if depreciation is taken into account and if animal spirits are somewhat (but not too) pessimistic. Combining these conditions with technological progress and wage bargaining, further analysis then indicates that in a profit-driven economy, the overall stability of the system is no longer guaranteed if zero growth is actively imposed, leading to a downward spiral, while in a wage-driven economy, stability can be induced under conditions of zero growth and technological progress but it may not be guaranteed for positive growth.</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Growth rate</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Growth models</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Studies</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economic growth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Recessions</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Keynesian theory</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2="8"><subfield code="i">Enthalten in</subfield><subfield code="t">Journal of post-Keynesian economics</subfield><subfield code="d">Philadelphia, Pa. : Routledge, Taylor & Francis Group, 1978</subfield><subfield code="g">37(2015), 4, Seite 623</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-627)130055077</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-600)436253-6</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-576)015592626</subfield><subfield code="x">0160-3477</subfield><subfield code="7">nnns</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="1" ind2="8"><subfield code="g">volume:37</subfield><subfield code="g">year:2015</subfield><subfield code="g">number:4</subfield><subfield code="g">pages:623</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="2"><subfield code="u">http://search.proquest.com/docview/1717299527</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_USEFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SYSFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_OLC</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SSG-OLC-WIW</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_11</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_21</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_26</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_70</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_2020</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4012</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4125</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4317</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4318</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4335</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4700</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="951" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">AR</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="952" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="d">37</subfield><subfield code="j">2015</subfield><subfield code="e">4</subfield><subfield code="h">623</subfield></datafield></record></collection>
|
score |
7.4014044 |