GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS
In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991),...
Ausführliche Beschreibung
Autor*in: |
Spear, Stephen [verfasserIn] |
---|
Format: |
Artikel |
---|---|
Sprache: |
Englisch |
Erschienen: |
2017 |
---|
Schlagwörter: |
---|
Übergeordnetes Werk: |
Enthalten in: Macroeconomic dynamics - Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997, 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 |
---|---|
Übergeordnetes Werk: |
volume:21 ; year:2017 ; number:2 ; pages:515-544 |
Links: |
---|
DOI / URN: |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 |
---|
Katalog-ID: |
OLC1993489053 |
---|
LEADER | 01000caa a2200265 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
001 | OLC1993489053 | ||
003 | DE-627 | ||
005 | 20230715050424.0 | ||
007 | tu | ||
008 | 170512s2017 xx ||||| 00| ||eng c | ||
024 | 7 | |a 10.1017/S1365100515000590 |2 doi | |
028 | 5 | 2 | |a PQ20170501 |
035 | |a (DE-627)OLC1993489053 | ||
035 | |a (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 | ||
035 | |a (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 | ||
035 | |a (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode | ||
040 | |a DE-627 |b ger |c DE-627 |e rakwb | ||
041 | |a eng | ||
082 | 0 | 4 | |a 330 |q ZDB |
100 | 1 | |a Spear, Stephen |e verfasserin |4 aut | |
245 | 1 | 0 | |a GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS |
264 | 1 | |c 2017 | |
336 | |a Text |b txt |2 rdacontent | ||
337 | |a ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen |b n |2 rdamedia | ||
338 | |a Band |b nc |2 rdacarrier | ||
520 | |a In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). | ||
650 | 4 | |a Growth models | |
650 | 4 | |a Macroeconomics | |
650 | 4 | |a Economic theory | |
650 | 4 | |a Studies | |
650 | 4 | |a Economic growth | |
700 | 1 | |a Young, Warren |4 oth | |
773 | 0 | 8 | |i Enthalten in |t Macroeconomic dynamics |d Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997 |g 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 |w (DE-627)240139984 |w (DE-600)1412233-9 |w (DE-576)067091768 |x 1365-1005 |7 nnns |
773 | 1 | 8 | |g volume:21 |g year:2017 |g number:2 |g pages:515-544 |
856 | 4 | 1 | |u http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 |3 Volltext |
856 | 4 | 2 | |u http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 |
912 | |a GBV_USEFLAG_A | ||
912 | |a SYSFLAG_A | ||
912 | |a GBV_OLC | ||
912 | |a SSG-OLC-WIW | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_26 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_70 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4012 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4126 | ||
912 | |a GBV_ILN_4311 | ||
951 | |a AR | ||
952 | |d 21 |j 2017 |e 2 |h 515-544 |
author_variant |
s s ss |
---|---|
matchkey_str |
article:13651005:2017----::eeaiainootmlrwhhoytcatcoesah |
hierarchy_sort_str |
2017 |
publishDate |
2017 |
allfields |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 doi PQ20170501 (DE-627)OLC1993489053 (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 330 ZDB Spear, Stephen verfasserin aut GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS 2017 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth Young, Warren oth Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 (DE-627)240139984 (DE-600)1412233-9 (DE-576)067091768 1365-1005 nnns volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 Volltext http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4126 GBV_ILN_4311 AR 21 2017 2 515-544 |
spelling |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 doi PQ20170501 (DE-627)OLC1993489053 (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 330 ZDB Spear, Stephen verfasserin aut GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS 2017 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth Young, Warren oth Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 (DE-627)240139984 (DE-600)1412233-9 (DE-576)067091768 1365-1005 nnns volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 Volltext http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4126 GBV_ILN_4311 AR 21 2017 2 515-544 |
allfields_unstemmed |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 doi PQ20170501 (DE-627)OLC1993489053 (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 330 ZDB Spear, Stephen verfasserin aut GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS 2017 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth Young, Warren oth Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 (DE-627)240139984 (DE-600)1412233-9 (DE-576)067091768 1365-1005 nnns volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 Volltext http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4126 GBV_ILN_4311 AR 21 2017 2 515-544 |
allfieldsGer |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 doi PQ20170501 (DE-627)OLC1993489053 (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 330 ZDB Spear, Stephen verfasserin aut GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS 2017 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth Young, Warren oth Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 (DE-627)240139984 (DE-600)1412233-9 (DE-576)067091768 1365-1005 nnns volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 Volltext http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4126 GBV_ILN_4311 AR 21 2017 2 515-544 |
allfieldsSound |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 doi PQ20170501 (DE-627)OLC1993489053 (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode DE-627 ger DE-627 rakwb eng 330 ZDB Spear, Stephen verfasserin aut GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS 2017 Text txt rdacontent ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen n rdamedia Band nc rdacarrier In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth Young, Warren oth Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 (DE-627)240139984 (DE-600)1412233-9 (DE-576)067091768 1365-1005 nnns volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 Volltext http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4126 GBV_ILN_4311 AR 21 2017 2 515-544 |
language |
English |
source |
Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 |
sourceStr |
Enthalten in Macroeconomic dynamics 21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544 volume:21 year:2017 number:2 pages:515-544 |
format_phy_str_mv |
Article |
institution |
findex.gbv.de |
topic_facet |
Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth |
dewey-raw |
330 |
isfreeaccess_bool |
false |
container_title |
Macroeconomic dynamics |
authorswithroles_txt_mv |
Spear, Stephen @@aut@@ Young, Warren @@oth@@ |
publishDateDaySort_date |
2017-01-01T00:00:00Z |
hierarchy_top_id |
240139984 |
dewey-sort |
3330 |
id |
OLC1993489053 |
language_de |
englisch |
fullrecord |
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim"><record><leader>01000caa a2200265 4500</leader><controlfield tag="001">OLC1993489053</controlfield><controlfield tag="003">DE-627</controlfield><controlfield tag="005">20230715050424.0</controlfield><controlfield tag="007">tu</controlfield><controlfield tag="008">170512s2017 xx ||||| 00| ||eng c</controlfield><datafield tag="024" ind1="7" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">10.1017/S1365100515000590</subfield><subfield code="2">doi</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="028" ind1="5" ind2="2"><subfield code="a">PQ20170501</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-627)OLC1993489053</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="b">ger</subfield><subfield code="c">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="e">rakwb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="041" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">eng</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="082" ind1="0" ind2="4"><subfield code="a">330</subfield><subfield code="q">ZDB</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="100" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Spear, Stephen</subfield><subfield code="e">verfasserin</subfield><subfield code="4">aut</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0"><subfield code="a">GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="264" ind1=" " ind2="1"><subfield code="c">2017</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="336" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Text</subfield><subfield code="b">txt</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacontent</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="337" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen</subfield><subfield code="b">n</subfield><subfield code="2">rdamedia</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="338" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Band</subfield><subfield code="b">nc</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacarrier</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49).</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Growth models</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Macroeconomics</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economic theory</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Studies</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economic growth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Young, Warren</subfield><subfield code="4">oth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2="8"><subfield code="i">Enthalten in</subfield><subfield code="t">Macroeconomic dynamics</subfield><subfield code="d">Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997</subfield><subfield code="g">21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-627)240139984</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-600)1412233-9</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-576)067091768</subfield><subfield code="x">1365-1005</subfield><subfield code="7">nnns</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="1" ind2="8"><subfield code="g">volume:21</subfield><subfield code="g">year:2017</subfield><subfield code="g">number:2</subfield><subfield code="g">pages:515-544</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="1"><subfield code="u">http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="2"><subfield code="u">http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_USEFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SYSFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_OLC</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SSG-OLC-WIW</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_26</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_70</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4012</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4126</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4311</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="951" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">AR</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="952" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="d">21</subfield><subfield code="j">2017</subfield><subfield code="e">2</subfield><subfield code="h">515-544</subfield></datafield></record></collection>
|
author |
Spear, Stephen |
spellingShingle |
Spear, Stephen ddc 330 misc Growth models misc Macroeconomics misc Economic theory misc Studies misc Economic growth GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS |
authorStr |
Spear, Stephen |
ppnlink_with_tag_str_mv |
@@773@@(DE-627)240139984 |
format |
Article |
dewey-ones |
330 - Economics |
delete_txt_mv |
keep |
author_role |
aut |
collection |
OLC |
remote_str |
false |
illustrated |
Not Illustrated |
issn |
1365-1005 |
topic_title |
330 ZDB GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS Growth models Macroeconomics Economic theory Studies Economic growth |
topic |
ddc 330 misc Growth models misc Macroeconomics misc Economic theory misc Studies misc Economic growth |
topic_unstemmed |
ddc 330 misc Growth models misc Macroeconomics misc Economic theory misc Studies misc Economic growth |
topic_browse |
ddc 330 misc Growth models misc Macroeconomics misc Economic theory misc Studies misc Economic growth |
format_facet |
Aufsätze Gedruckte Aufsätze |
format_main_str_mv |
Text Zeitschrift/Artikel |
carriertype_str_mv |
nc |
author2_variant |
w y wy |
hierarchy_parent_title |
Macroeconomic dynamics |
hierarchy_parent_id |
240139984 |
dewey-tens |
330 - Economics |
hierarchy_top_title |
Macroeconomic dynamics |
isfreeaccess_txt |
false |
familylinks_str_mv |
(DE-627)240139984 (DE-600)1412233-9 (DE-576)067091768 |
title |
GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS |
ctrlnum |
(DE-627)OLC1993489053 (DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053 (PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60 (KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode |
title_full |
GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS |
author_sort |
Spear, Stephen |
journal |
Macroeconomic dynamics |
journalStr |
Macroeconomic dynamics |
lang_code |
eng |
isOA_bool |
false |
dewey-hundreds |
300 - Social sciences |
recordtype |
marc |
publishDateSort |
2017 |
contenttype_str_mv |
txt |
container_start_page |
515 |
author_browse |
Spear, Stephen |
container_volume |
21 |
class |
330 ZDB |
format_se |
Aufsätze |
author-letter |
Spear, Stephen |
doi_str_mv |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 |
dewey-full |
330 |
title_sort |
generalizations of optimal growth theory: stochastic models, mathematics, and metasynthesis |
title_auth |
GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS |
abstract |
In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). |
abstractGer |
In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). |
abstract_unstemmed |
In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49). |
collection_details |
GBV_USEFLAG_A SYSFLAG_A GBV_OLC SSG-OLC-WIW GBV_ILN_26 GBV_ILN_70 GBV_ILN_4012 GBV_ILN_4126 GBV_ILN_4311 |
container_issue |
2 |
title_short |
GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS |
url |
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590 http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229 |
remote_bool |
false |
author2 |
Young, Warren |
author2Str |
Young, Warren |
ppnlink |
240139984 |
mediatype_str_mv |
n |
isOA_txt |
false |
hochschulschrift_bool |
false |
author2_role |
oth |
doi_str |
10.1017/S1365100515000590 |
up_date |
2024-07-03T14:41:53.212Z |
_version_ |
1803569293653180416 |
fullrecord_marcxml |
<?xml version="1.0" encoding="UTF-8"?><collection xmlns="http://www.loc.gov/MARC21/slim"><record><leader>01000caa a2200265 4500</leader><controlfield tag="001">OLC1993489053</controlfield><controlfield tag="003">DE-627</controlfield><controlfield tag="005">20230715050424.0</controlfield><controlfield tag="007">tu</controlfield><controlfield tag="008">170512s2017 xx ||||| 00| ||eng c</controlfield><datafield tag="024" ind1="7" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">10.1017/S1365100515000590</subfield><subfield code="2">doi</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="028" ind1="5" ind2="2"><subfield code="a">PQ20170501</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-627)OLC1993489053</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(DE-599)GBVOLC1993489053</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(PRQ)c1300-260052a6cfc392b09b8a76076928c2d6e8bc26f32224c2522a19d85aab0d50c60</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="035" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">(KEY)0328579020170000021000200515generalizationsofoptimalgrowththeorystochasticmode</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="040" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="b">ger</subfield><subfield code="c">DE-627</subfield><subfield code="e">rakwb</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="041" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">eng</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="082" ind1="0" ind2="4"><subfield code="a">330</subfield><subfield code="q">ZDB</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="100" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Spear, Stephen</subfield><subfield code="e">verfasserin</subfield><subfield code="4">aut</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="245" ind1="1" ind2="0"><subfield code="a">GENERALIZATIONS OF OPTIMAL GROWTH THEORY: STOCHASTIC MODELS, MATHEMATICS, AND METASYNTHESIS</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="264" ind1=" " ind2="1"><subfield code="c">2017</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="336" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Text</subfield><subfield code="b">txt</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacontent</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="337" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">ohne Hilfsmittel zu benutzen</subfield><subfield code="b">n</subfield><subfield code="2">rdamedia</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="338" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Band</subfield><subfield code="b">nc</subfield><subfield code="2">rdacarrier</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="520" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">In previous papers [Spear and Young (2014, 2015)], we surveyed the origins, evolution, and dissemination of optimal growth, two-sector and turnpike models up to the early 1970s. Regarding subsequent developments in growth theory, a number of prominent observers, such as Fischer (1988), Stern (1991), and McCallum (1996), maintained that after significant progress in the 1950s and 1960s, economic growth theory "received relatively little attention for almost two decades" [Fischer (1988, p. 329)], and that "by the late 1960s early 1970s, research on the theory of growth more or less stopped" [Stern (1991, p. 259)]. Stern went on to say "the latter half of the 1980s saw a rekindling of growth theory, particularly in the work of Romer . . . and Lucas" (1991, p. 259), that is to say, in the form of "endogenous growth" models. McCallum, for his part, wrote (1996, p. 41), "After a long period of quiescence, growth economics has in the last decade (1986-1995) become an extremely active area of research." Moreover, Brock and Mirman's (1972b) paper was the sole "extension" of Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans to a "stochastic environment" mentioned by McCallum (1996, 49).</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Growth models</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Macroeconomics</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economic theory</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Studies</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="650" ind1=" " ind2="4"><subfield code="a">Economic growth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="700" ind1="1" ind2=" "><subfield code="a">Young, Warren</subfield><subfield code="4">oth</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="0" ind2="8"><subfield code="i">Enthalten in</subfield><subfield code="t">Macroeconomic dynamics</subfield><subfield code="d">Cambridge : Cambridge Univ. Press, 1997</subfield><subfield code="g">21(2017), 2, Seite 515-544</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-627)240139984</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-600)1412233-9</subfield><subfield code="w">(DE-576)067091768</subfield><subfield code="x">1365-1005</subfield><subfield code="7">nnns</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="773" ind1="1" ind2="8"><subfield code="g">volume:21</subfield><subfield code="g">year:2017</subfield><subfield code="g">number:2</subfield><subfield code="g">pages:515-544</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="1"><subfield code="u">http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000590</subfield><subfield code="3">Volltext</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="856" ind1="4" ind2="2"><subfield code="u">http://search.proquest.com/docview/1869001229</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_USEFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SYSFLAG_A</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_OLC</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">SSG-OLC-WIW</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_26</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_70</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4012</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4126</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="912" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">GBV_ILN_4311</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="951" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="a">AR</subfield></datafield><datafield tag="952" ind1=" " ind2=" "><subfield code="d">21</subfield><subfield code="j">2017</subfield><subfield code="e">2</subfield><subfield code="h">515-544</subfield></datafield></record></collection>
|
score |
7.402231 |